eCommons

 

Essays on Social Policy in Victorian England

Other Titles

Abstract

On the day she died---January 22nd, 1901---Victoria was Britain's longest reigning monarch. Britain (and the world) had been transformed during her reign. It had elected ten prime ministers, including Russell, Palmerston, and Disraeli twice; Derby and Salisbury thrice; and Gladstone four times. The United States had elected eighteen presidents. Van Buren was inaugurated only 481 days before her coronation. McKinley was shot only 227 days after her death. Between 1837 and 1901, Britain's population had more than doubled. Where in 1837 there was little but arable- or pasture-land, in 1901 there were cities, roads, railroads, new industries, and new forms of local government. This transformation, however salutary, was profoundly disruptive. There was immigration into Britain. There was immigration within Britain. Infrastructure was built. Vaccinations were discovered. The business cycle displaced meteorology as the most important source of economic uncertainty. In the following three essays, I explore three reactions to these sundry disruptions. In the first essay, I explore the Public Health Act of 1848---England's first attempt at systematic sanitation reform---and, in so doing, I provide quantitative evidence of the effect of public health interventions on mortality in a decidedly developing country. Between 1848 and 1870, the Public Health Act oversaw the adoption of more than 600 local boards of health (which, combined, affected roughly one-quarter of the English population). The Act endowed these boards with the power to tax, borrow, regulate, provide sanitary services, and build, re-build, seize, or otherwise alter local infrastructure. Since the jurisdictions of local boards of health and the jurisdictions of Poor Law unions (i.e., the local geographical units within which mortality statistics were recorded) were not coterminous, the mortality effects of the Public Health Act have been largely unexplored. I introduce a new panel dataset that maps the jurisdictions of local boards of health into the jurisdictions of Poor Law unions. I then leverage variation in both the timing and extent of board adoption across Poor Law unions in order to estimate the cumulative effect of the adoption of a local board of health on mortality 1, 2, 3, and 4 years after adoption. My estimates suggest that the adoption of a union-wide local board of health reduced mortality by 14.2 percent after four years, that approximately 225,000 lives were saved by local boards of health between 1848 and 1870, and that the aggregate English mortality rate was 3.7 percent lower in 1870 than it would have been had the Public Health Act not been passed. In the second essay, I explore the relationship between welfare generosity and welfare caseloads. Between 1601 and 1948, the English welfare system was the Poor Law. It provided working-class men, women, and children with a vital, if meager, guarantee of support in the event that they sustained a negative income shock. According to many contemporaries, it also encouraged indolence. In the late 1860s and 1870s, objections to any guarantee of support grew more vocal and more politically formidable. Some localities began to relieve a significantly greater proportion of welfare recipients in workhouses---deliberately disagreeable dwellings intended to disincentivize welfare recipiency. This movement was, in effect, a de facto, decentralized welfare reform. I use variation in the change in the proportion of welfare recipients relieved in workhouses between 1865 and 1880 across English localities to estimate the effect of workhouse use on the rate of welfare recipiency. First, I introduce a new panel dataset of Poor Law unions---local geographical units that administered the Poor Law, of which there were approximately 600. Second, I employ a difference-in-differences model to estimate whether and to what extent the workhouse affected the rate of welfare recipiency. I find that approximately three in four welfare applicants to whom the workhouse was offered as a "test" refused the offer. I also find that this "workhouse effect" was insufficiently large to meaningfully reduce the costs associated with the workhouse. Third, I employ a triple-difference model to estimate whether welfare applicants to whom the workhouse was offered were more likely to reject the offer if the workhouses in which they would be relieved were deficient in ventilation, water supply, general sanitation, or diet. I find that they were not. In the third essay, I explore the relationship between wealth and welfare generosity. Were, for example, wealthier people or places more or less likely to favor redistributive policies, such as a welfare system, because of their wealth? I isolate quasi-experimental variation in per capita property wealth across English Poor Law unions to quantify the causal effect of wealth on welfare generosity. Poor Law unions were local geographical units, of which there were approximately 600 in 1881, that administered the English welfare system. They were, for all intents and purposes, autonomous mini-welfare states, in each of which a board of guardians determined the level of generosity. They were also agglomerations of parishes---hyper-local geographical units, of which there were approximately 14,000 in 1881. Each parish was entitled to a certain, pre-determined number of guardians to represent it on the board of the Poor Law union to which it belonged. Guardians were rarely apportioned to parishes in proportion to their population. Some parishes---typically the wealthiest, least populous parishes within a Poor Law union---were over-represented. Others---typically the poorest, most populous parishes within a Poor Law union---were under-represented. Moreover, the extent of the over-representation of the wealthiest parishes varied across Poor Law unions. This is the variation that I leverage. I introduce a new dataset that includes the number of guardians, the population, and the property wealth of each English parish, as well as two distinct measures of the welfare generosity of each English Poor Law union. I then use a measure of the malapportionment of guardians---and, consequently, of the over-representation of wealth on boards of guardians---as an instrument for wealth. This instrument is both strongly correlated with wealth (by construction) and uncorrelated with all other union-level variables that are both available and potentially related to welfare generosity. I find that wealth itself caused neither an increase nor a decrease in welfare generosity.

Journal / Series

Volume & Issue

Description

Sponsorship

Date Issued

2019-08-30

Publisher

Keywords

Economics; Public policy; Economic history

Location

Effective Date

Expiration Date

Sector

Employer

Union

Union Local

NAICS

Number of Workers

Committee Chair

Boyer, George R

Committee Co-Chair

Committee Member

Lovenheim, Michael F.
Sanders, Nicholas James

Degree Discipline

Economics

Degree Name

Ph.D., Economics

Degree Level

Doctor of Philosophy

Related Version

Related DOI

Related To

Related Part

Based on Related Item

Has Other Format(s)

Part of Related Item

Related To

Related Publication(s)

Link(s) to Related Publication(s)

References

Link(s) to Reference(s)

Previously Published As

Government Document

ISBN

ISMN

ISSN

Other Identifiers

Rights

Rights URI

Types

dissertation or thesis

Accessibility Feature

Accessibility Hazard

Accessibility Summary

Link(s) to Catalog Record